Thursday, 18 September 2025

Will the Employment Rights Bill help or hurt growth?

 

  

1.      The Employment Rights Bill is making its way through the UK Parliament at the moment. There are a lot of details, set out in, for example, the Impact Assessment,  here.  Among the provisions quoted there are unfair dismissal, paternity and sick pay rights from the first day of employment, repealing laws that require minimum service levels in some industries during strikes, strengthening union rights etc.

2.      What will the effects be on growth? Since the government says its entire policy is about growth this is an important question.

3.      To understand the effect on growth it will be helpful to understand the effect on investment. The graph below makes dismal reading. Using the OECD index of employment regulation, there's a negative relationship which is that more employment regulation means less intangible investment. To the extent that intangible investment is important for growth, this is bad news for the policy.

 

 

Source: own calculations

 

4.      This graph might seem obvious. But a moment's reflection raises a few puzzles. First, if the cost of employing workers goes up firms would presumably substitute towards capital. That should tell you that more employment regulation would give you more investment, not less.  Second, the proponents of this bill argue that it will make workers happier and productivity will go up for that reason.

5.      So what's going on?

6.      Let's start by thinking about investment. There are two important effects of costs on investment.

a.      The first is the cost of capital effect. Once the firm has decided to invest, other things equal, a fall in the cost of capital, say from a tax break, will make the firm invest more. By this logic, a rise in the price of labour, due to this bill, lowers the relative cost of capital relative to labour, thereby potentially raising investment. This logic gives rise to the first part of the puzzle above.

b.     But there is an important second effect on investment. The outcome of investment is uncertain. Further, much investment is sunk, which is to say that it is often difficult to get that investment back once you have made it.  Think for example about Nokia's investment in software which became Windows Mobile. When the market for Nokia's mobile phones collapsed, around $5 billion worth of software investment had to be just written off. This is important because the cost of capital effect applies once the firm is actually decided to invest. But the uncertainty effect means that a rise in uncertainty makes the firm postpone its decision to invest. With uncertainty and sunk capital, there is an additional cost of investment, which is that investing today costs the firm the value of waiting.  That waiting has value (formally an option value), since underlying uncertainty might be resolved in the future.

7.      So the Bill has potentially two effects. The cost of capital effect is good for investment, because it raises the relative price of labour. The uncertainty effect is bad for investment, because firms will postpone investment until the uncertain costs are clearer.

8.      What then will we expect? My best prediction is that the employment rights bill is a rise in uncertainty for firms. The reason is that these employment rights are set out in broad outline in the bill, but then end up being interpreted by the courts.. The backlog of court cases is now over a year. It will in practise take a long time for the full implications of these employment rights to become clear to firms.  Look for example at the avalanche of cases around equal pay, the Next case for example ((https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/media/66d190b2bdecebe01a183399/Miss_M_Thandi___Others_V__Next_Retail_Limited_-1302019-2018-Resreved_Judgment.pdf). .  These cases have taken years, and in the case of retailers precede retailer by retailer.

9.      In case this might seem a matter of theoretical curiosity it is worth remembering the effects of Brexit are precisely this uncertainty effect. As Josh Martin and I showed, after the Brexit referendum investment literally stopped in its tracks for many years. A significant slowdown in growth thereby followed.

10. This uncertainty effect explains why the bill would likely particularly affect intangible investment. Intangible investment is likely to be more sunk, more company and market specific than tangible investment: British Airways can always sell its planes, but much harder to sell its brand name. This in turn is why the cross country evidence sometimes finds employment market regulation is negatively correlated with investment and sometimes positively correlated: It depends upon whether the underlying investment considered is both sunk and if the regulation is uncertain.

11. Finally, moving outside investment, some remarks. 

12. First, my baseline model of the labour market is a simple one: there are wage and non-wage attributes of every job.  The non-wage attributes are, for example, paid tea-breaks, effort on the job and contractual form (employees v freelancers for example).

13. Second, the CMA has done an extensive study of the presence of “monoposony” power in labour markets (Competition and market power in UK labour markets, CMA Microeconomics Unit 25 January 2024 Report no. 1).  This is hard to do, since we don’t really know what the labour market is, especially in the era of working from home.  Taking the “labour” market as the Travel to Work Area, they find

a.      87% of workers work in “low-concentration” labour markets (in 2019, that fell to 80% in the unusual conditions of the pandemic), see p.104

 

b.     The effect of moving between concentrations is not large.  (para 5.14, see also the notes to figure 21),  “…an increase in concentration …by 10% …would be associated with just a 0.1% fall in wages.”.  This means that going from medium concentration, 2,500 to low, 1,500 which is a 51 log point change would change wages by ½ a percent.

14. Further work by the CMA, on my reading at least, has not found widespread product market monopoly power either (except in some cases).  It seems unlikely to me then that monopoly and monoposony power is widespread.  Thus the first-order effect of a rise in costs on firms will be adjustment of wage and non-wage margins, or, if this is not possible (due to wage floors for example), adjustment of quantities.  Thus the assumption that workers will be “happier” and so more productive after the  passing of the bill seems questionable; we don’t know what other margins will adjust.  For example, the Next case found that following the minimum wage, Next abolished paid rest breaks (unpaid rest breaks were the industry norm so this was reverting to the industry standard).