Monday, 30 November 2020

Supply chains and the UK productivity puzzle: a framework

An interesting Productivity Institute meeting today on supply chains. 

One of the features discussed about the UK productivity puzzle is under the heading of “supply chain management”.  Maybe British supply chain productivity is very low. Maybe British supply chain productivity is not resilient enough, see COVID and issues around Chinese involvement in 3G technology for example.  so how should we think about supply chains? How should we answer questions about whether supply chain management is or is not adequate?

Let's start with an example.  Suppose we have three types of law firms.

1.     Law firm 1 employes a building, a receptionist, an operations manager, and a load of lawyers.  The process within the law firm consists of the following.  The client comes into the building and is greeted by the receptionist who then takes the client up to the lawyer.  The lawyer gives the client an opinion , and the client pays and walks away.  The operations manager designs the process by which the receptionist takes the client up to the lawyer (offering them tea, helping with directions to the next appointment etc.)  Notice, the client never sees the operations manager, and although the client sees the receptionist, neither the receptionist nor the ops manager is a trained lawyer.

2.     We then have some definitions as follows:

a.      Industry.  the law firm is in the law industry because its output is legal services.

b.     Process. The visible processes which the law firm is involved in consists of the process carried out by the receptionist and the process carried out by the lawyer.

c.      Activity.  The law firm is in fact involved in three different activities:

                                                                         i.      the provision of reception services,

                                                                       ii.      of operations services ,

                                                                    iii.      and legal advice. 

d.     Lots of the lawyers in law firms moan endlessly about the fact that out of their fees comes the expenses of the receptionists and the operations managers, none of whom know anything about the law. Likewise academics who complain about administrators and admission staff who know nothing about academia, footballers who complain about groundstaff who can't play football etc.

3.     now consider law firm 2. They have contracted out reception services to a separate firm, who has simply bolted a flat screen TV screen to the wall of the front office and provides receptionist services remotely.

4.     Now consider law firm 3. They have also contracted at reception services, but they as well they have contracted out operations management to a management consultant. the management consultant as supplied them with the book setting out a set of routines to which, let us say, the receptionist adheres, when taking the client up to the lawyer.

 

What can we say about productivity and the adequacy or otherwise of supply chain management in these examples?

1.     Let's start with the definition of a supply chain. Law firm one has an entirely internal supply chain, in this case the process by which the receptionist hands over the client to the lawyer. That supply chain is presided over by the operations manager.  Law firm three has a supply chain, but it is external. That is to say, the services provided by the receptionist and by the operations manager in simply bought in externally.

2.     Going back to the activities that are involved, in firm one the operations manager provides operations advice services, but this is done internally. If one had the management accounts for this firm, and one could figure out the wages and overhead costs of the operations manager, one could therefore figure out the costs involved in the provision of those advice services. In case 3 the matter is much easier; one just looks at how much the firm is paying to the management consultant.

3.     What about measuring productivity? there would seem to be two methods:

4.     method 1.  Process.

a.      In law firm one, break up the firm into the different processes that are involved. Try to measure the productivity of each process. So there will in practise be two output measures; first, the output of the reception process, and 2nd the output of offering legal advice after the client has been through the process of reception.

b.     In this case, one would have to try as well to allocate costs such as the operations manager into each process. This of course it's much easier to do in the case of law firm 3 since every part of the process is transacted for. Thus there is going to be an observable price and quantity for the entire provision of legal advice.

5.     Method 2.  Activity.

a.      For every law firm count the output as the provision of legal advice, so there is only one measure of output. However, account for the fact that different law firms undertake different activities, and these activities might potentially contribute to productivity. In each of the examples the activities are (a) reception activities, (b) giving-legal-advice-activities, and (c) operations activities.  

b.     Although measuring the activities is hard, by taking an activities rather than a process approach, one avoids the almost impossible problem of subdividing the output of legal advice into lots of different processes.  Indeed, in many law firms , who keep time sheets of chargeable hours, it might very well be feasible to gather data on the activity, because it is the different activities that are documented on the charge sheets (for example many charge sheets might categorise the activities of being with clients, marketing and customer acquisition, personnel and administration). 

c.  This activity approach would, under certain circumstances, count the knowledge of the ops manager as an intangible asset.  For more on intangibles, see here

6.     (Finally, an overall point on the economic modelling of all of this.  As Milgrom, Roberts and others Have pointed out, economists have a very stripped down model of the firm. When economists write down what is called a production function, they assert, on the face of it quite sensibly, the output is produced by capital and Labour. What many supply chain managers and the academics who study them will tell you is that production requires as well coordination activities. Economists tend not to bother modelling these coordination activities separately. They are either included in labour, or viewed as being small enough for one to ignore.)

 

 

 


Thursday, 26 November 2020

R&D and intangible investment: evidence from a survey

 In our work on intangibles, we keep stressing that it is broader than R&D.  Here's some evidence 


" Research comprised a telephone survey of 625 respondents across nine creative industry sub-sectors and was undertaken before the COVID-19 lockdown."


"This report considers R&D in the creative industries using two existing definitions: the broad OECD Frascati definition, used in official international surveys, and the definition used by HMRC for tax credit purposes. More than half (55%) of firms had undertaken R&D using the broad Frascati definition but only 14% had done so using the definition for tax. IT, software & computer services firms were the most likely to have conducted R&D activity under either definition (71%), with museums, galleries & libraries least likely (27%)."


In more detail, firms were asked a broad and narrow definition of R&D.  Here's the questions and the answers: 







Monday, 16 November 2020

AI in the Post COVID-19 Economic Recovery

 AI evidence to the All Party group on AI. Evidence pack here

Thursday, 12 November 2020

Working from home

 

Notes on WFH

This has become super popular in the literature.  Let’s be careful not to get overexcited, and, for those who are in the professional and white collar sector, not to extrapolate too much from their own personal observation .

 

The ONS publishes data on working from home in their fantastic Business Impact of Coronavirus (COVID-19) Survey (BICS). Here are weighted results from Wave 16, link being:

https://www.ons.gov.uk/economy/economicoutputandproductivity/output/datasets/businessimpactofcovid19surveybicsresults

and specifically

https://www.ons.gov.uk/file?uri=%2feconomy%2feconomicoutputandproductivity%2foutput%2fdatasets%2fbusinessimpactofcovid19surveybicsresults%2fbicswave16/bicswave162supressed.xlsx

 

The table below shows some of the key figures. They start in column one and column 2 by asking firms whether more or less of their workers are working from home, referring to the week 5th -1th October. Perhaps not surprisingly 26% on average in all industries of workers are working more from home, although 75% report no increase in working from home. Notice that the biggest increase in the number of workers working from home is in the water and sewerage industry , at 85%. Even in manufacturing, where you would imagine working from home would be rather complicated, 24% more workers are working from home.

 


 

 

 

A snapshot of working from home may not be very informative. Perhaps it's of more information therefore to ask firms whether they expect not working from home will be a permanent feature. This is set out in columns 8 and 9 (with 10 for not sure). In column 8 we can see that 17% of all industries 17% expect working from home to be a permanent feature of their business model. 65% do not expect it to be the case and 17% don't know. Returning to the water industry only 2% of firms expect this to be a permanent feature and 93% of firms expected not to be the case.

Notice that there are really only three industries which stand out as expecting working from home to be a permanent feature: information and communication and professional and scientific and education. There is fairly clear blue water between the numbers in those sectors, 37 percent, 34% at 28% and the other sectors.  This immediately suggests that perhaps the discussion of working from home might be dominated by the bias of those people who are typically writing about it.

 

Finally, we may look at the consequences of working from home for productivity. These are in columns 4,5 and 6. Perhaps the most striking result is how balanced these results are. Around 60% of firms think that productivity will be the same 19% of firms think that productivity will go down , and 14% of firms think the productivity will go up.  Once again the numbers who think productivity will rise are concentrated in a rather small number of industries most notably 46% in information and communications and 52% in other services.  Professional scientific and administrative have numbers at around 10% but otherwise none of the other industries have a particularly strong expectation of an increase in productivity.

 

Finally the scatter plot summarises some of these numbers. The vertical axis is the number expecting long run increase in WFH less those expecting long run decrease. The horizontal axis we have the net numbers in the industries who expect productivity to increase .

 


As we see in the scatter, the bulk of the industries are at the bottom left. There is some small expected increase in the numbers working from home, but productivity or net is anticipated to be lower. Rather few industries are in the top right where productivity is expected on net to increase and there was to be substantial more working from home. These are dominated essentially by ICT , other services and professional scientific and technical, where there is expected to be, on net a slight loss in productivity.  Notice finally the all industries: on 48% more firms expect less WFH then expect more WFH and 5% more of firms expect productivity to fall.


Update:

Finally, ONS also ask business who say they will have more (less) working from home why they intend to do so (not to do so) .  Of businesses not intending, 91% say that’s unsuitable for their business. Of those intending, we have

a.       64% say lower overheads

b.       61% improved staff wellbeing

c.       40% increased staff productivity

d.       22% ability to recruit from wider pool

e.       18% reduced sickness

f.        11% better able to match jobs with skills

 

 


Friday, 6 November 2020

Knowledge spillovers and corporate investment in scientifc research

 This paper looks, using patents at how scientific resesarch is used in firms.  Here are some points I took away


1. R versus D

Do universities do all the "basic" research? No.  "

In 2017, the business sector funded about $85 billion in basic and applied research, accounting for about 22% of R&D funded by business, and 43% of all research in the United States".

 Figure 1 gives a sense of this


" Figure 1, which is based on National Science Foundation data, shows that the share of basic and applied research in the total domestic R&D funded and performed by corporations, the \R" of R&D, in the United States has declined from over 31 percent in 1985 to about 20 percent in 2008 and has remained at that level thereafter. The share of research in total R&D performed by business shows a similar, albeit less dramatic, decline, from a peak of around 30 percent in 1991 to about 20 percent in 2008, and rising modestly thereafter. These trends suggest that the composition of corporate R&D is shifting away from \R" and towards \D".

 

And figure 2 shows some more:

 

 "Many corporate labs were shut down or were oriented towards more applied activities. Bell Labs was separated from its parent company AT&T and placed under Lucent in 1996; Xerox PARC was spun o into a separate company in 2002, and Du Pont closed its Central Research and Developmet Laboratory in 2016.33 These trends are also re
ected in Figure 2, which presents trends in the annual number of publications (\R") and patent (\D") divided by sales, for our sample firms. The corporate publication rate fell by about 60% over the sample period, whereas patenting rates do not show any clear trend. The pattern suggests that the composition of corporate R&D is changing over time, with less \R" and more \D""

2. What about spillovers? Well, corporate scientists write papers and so disclose results. Isn't that a receipe for disaster, firms are giving away their own discoveries?  maybe not. Perhaps the performing of basic scientific research  enables firms to absorb research better, or provide careers for top scientists etc

And it looks like more knowledge is spilling over:


 

 

 

 

 

3.  At the same time, another paper by the authors has documented that firms are doing less research than they were.  So:

In this paper, we argue that private returns to corporate research depend on the balance between two opposing forces: the benefi ts from the use of science in own inventions, and costs of spillovers to rivals. ...increases in spillovers relative to internal use may be a proximate cause of the decline in corporate research that the literature has documented"

 

4. They match together US companies who spend on R&D and had  and at least one patent over the period 1980-2015 (an unbalanced panel of 3,807 rms).  (This is a major task since patents and companies can change ownership).  They 

We measure the use
of internal research in invention by citations made by the firm's patents to its own scienti fc publications. Spillovers are measured by citations from the patents of rivals to the focal firm's publications.

5. what do they find?

First, we show that there is a positive relationship between the market value of a firm and its stock of scienti c output. This relationship is stronger when the firm's patents use the science that the firm's
scientists produce.


Second, and consistent with this, we find that a firm produces
more scientifi c publications if it is more likely to use the science in its patents, but produces fewer publications if the science is more likely to be used by rivals' inventions.

 6. This raises a series of questions.

    a.  other work finds that "ideas are getting harder to find".  Perhaps this is because firms are doing less R, and even if universities are doing it, they might not be as good.

b. but then the question is why are firms doing less R? this paper would say that doing less will hurt them since they cannot benefit from their own research, but doing less helps them if more of it is spilling over to others. 

The paper offers some reasons:

1. product market competition has become more intensive? No, if any thing the other way?

2. IP has got tighter? Maybe in the 1980s, but not recently. And anyway, life sciences, where patents are the tightest have not declined as much as other sectors.