Wednesday 13 May 2020

Teaching Link: Imperial college student webinar, Current economic prospects, 12 May 2020



Imperial college student webinar, Current economic prospects, 12 May 2020
Some of our Imperial College students organised a webinar last night on our current economic prospects. They kindly invited David Shepherd, David Miles, James Sefton and me to participate. Here are some notes on the questions that they set us in advance and a few notes on what was said. Thanks to our talented and interested students for organising this and participating.

Q. How does the current climate compare to previous periods of economic turbulence e.g. Spanish flu of 1918, WW I&II, the great depression? In your opinion what is the optimal fiscal/monetary policy mix to confront the liquidity crunch due to COVID? 

The BBC showed on its website the following graph saying that this was the sharpest annual downturn since 1706. So this is clearly an gigantic recession; historically unparalleled, at least since 1706m and rolling together The Great Depression, the 2008 Financial Crisis and the flu pandemic all in one go. 




Optimal mix.
The optimal mix of money in fiscal policy is a nice question. Perhaps the best way to think about it is the benchmark economics competitive model. In that model economic systems are self-correcting. If there’s a shock to a market, say to the demand for PPE, it becomes more expensive: demand is choked off and supply is increased, as firms rush to enter a more lucrative market. The two forces of falling demand and rising supply raise prices and bring the market back to equilibrium.

The second feature of the benchmark competitive economics model, is that markets are not only self correcting, but they are what economists call complete. By complete this means that goods can be transacted for. And, in particular, future goods can be transacted for via future contracts.  Of course that's exactly what we see in the real world if we're thinking about let us say oil or aluminium. Airlines buy the oil forward . And that's part of prudent business management. But when economists think of a complete market they mean that all items can be traded forward. As John Kay is pointed out, in his book “The Truth About Markets” that would mean that you could buy a futures contract in let us say 1960 for the appearance of an iPad in 1990. The fact is of course that nobody even knew what an iPad was in 1960, let alone were able to sign a contract for it. But had they done so, it would have meant that the contract could have been traded and the forces of supply and demand mentioned above would have equilibrated the market.

Now in an economy where neither of those two conditions hold then we potentially have a room for policy. Let's take the first one. Many markets especially financial markets, seemed to be complete opposite of self equilibrating, especially in periods when market participants are panicking. That is to say uncertainty over the future, which induces panic, often makes sellers of financial assets sell, without demanders coming in to pull up the price (Think of somebody who are forced into crisis to sell some asset, a so called fire sale , even when the market is very depressed). The price of the asset falls and falls, thereby amplifying the original shock.

As for the second condition, nobody knew what COVID19 was and nobody signed a contract on it: in this case nobody insured themselves against its possibility. So we've had a very large adverse shock against which nobody took out insurance.

So the role of the state in this case , is to (1) step in if the market is in chaos and (2) to provide insurance because of the incompleteness in that market.

One important role for monetary policy is to step in when financial markets are in chaos and are dysfunctional. The Monetary Policy Committee did this in the financial crisis.

As for insurance, that is commonly the right role for fiscal policy. The benefit system ensures that workers have unemployment benefits if they were unlucky enough to be unemployed, and the progressivity of the tax system is such that when incomes go down taxes are effectively cut, so-called automatic stabilisers. That provisioning of insurance of course involves borrowing and involves perhaps paying out large amounts of unemployment benefit now, to be funded by the state, but then paid back by future taxing and borrowing once the economy has been restored.  

The right mix of monetary and fiscal policy depends upon institutions that we currently have in place.  The burden of insurance provision should lie with the fiscal authorities. Note however that as part of inflation targeting an independent central bank might want to undertake more expansionary monetary policy than would otherwise be the case if it wanted to avoid scarring; that is to say, if its inflation target would be imperilled if a prolonged recession lowered the potential output in the economy.   See Powell’s speech today (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/other20200228a.htm).


·         Do you expect a mild recession with a V shape recovery, a greater recession with a U shaped recovery or an L shaped deep depression? What are 'the city' thinking and how are they modelling excess risk/uncertainty into long-term economic models/predictions?


In our most recent monthly policy report The Bank of England have felt that the situation is so uncertain, and the historical parallels so difficult to discern, that it is unable to have a definitive forecast . Instead it produced a scenario, being an outlook based on the series of what at the time seem reasonable judgments. That scenario in Chart 1.3 below has a very sharp fall in GDP and then a slow recovery.  So overall UK GDP falls by 14% in 2020. Activity then picks up in the latter part of 2020 and into 2021 as social distancing measures are relaxed. That said GDP doesn't reach the pre covid level until the second half of 2021. So in 2020 GDP falls by 14%, in 2021 it rises by 15% and in 2022 it rises by 3%.

. 



The chart below shows what other forecasters expect for 2020 Q 2. The bank is somewhere in the middle of these averages. 

The report notes a number of downside risks to this scenario. One of course is the position of the world which is currently extremely difficult. A second which other commentators have looked at is the possibility of further waves of the pandemic. This is obviously a matter for epidemiologists but it is of interest to look at the chart below, put together by some London Business School economists pointing out that belief the death rate from Spanish flu came in three waves.  It is perhaps also worth pointing out do we don't yet have a vaccine for AIDS, thus the question of whether we will eventually have a vaccine is still open one .  Still another important point came out in the discussion last night. It is that it's very difficult to know how to interpret the recent fall and death rates because we are so uncertain as to what the level of infection in the community might be. The range of estimates seems to be from 5 to 65%. Of course, if the level of infection is very high, this is potentially extremely good and important news, because it means that the lockdown can be released. We urgently need to know what this number is. Perhaps the proliferation of tracing apps, the national launch of the NHS app, and Professor Tim Spector’s app from Kings College might help us.








Finally, the other sets of sensitivities would be around scarring. As mentioned above this is the possibility that the long-term supply potential of the economy is so damaged that it is difficult for the economy to come back again consistent with low inflation.  A number of scarring mechanisms exist. One is obviously the idea that if there was an extended period of unemployment workers would lose their skills and motivation. The second is that there may be a permanent structural change in the economy such that a number of capital assets (think airports) are simply as not usable and productive in the current economy as before. Of course capital can be reallocated but if that takes a time then the supplies potentially the economy can potentially be disrupted.  And of course it does look like they're going to be need to be some capital assets which will have to be increased: say, hospitals, delivery equipment and social distancing infrastructure.


·         What will be the long term impact of QE/Debt monetisation on interest rates and inflation post-COVID?  How will we pay-off the debt: taxation, austerity, growth, or a combination of the three? How does this marry-up with political decision-making and public opinion?

This raises a number of key questions. Let's go through them one by one .

The first point is what will happen to R*. To recap R*is the neutral rate of interest , that is to say the rate of interest at which resources completely utilised, and  unemployment and inflation are stable. It is indeed the case that central banks can influence short term interest rates but the long term interest rate is something typically beyond their control. So for example the large increase in demographic ageing in the last 30 years and the associated high demand for savings for a longer old age, is widely held to have depressed the equilibrium interest rate. Equally there appears to have been a fall in the demand for capital, perhaps caused by the increase of use of intangible assets which likewise pressed down on the equilibrium long term interest rate. So the key question is what happens to that future interest rate after this crisis?

One possibility is that it will increase as the demand for capital and demand for debt rises in the face of large borrowing by central banks and governments. Against that if there were an outbreak of precautionary savings in the face of the uncertainty around this shock , then there will be strong pressure for the rate to fall even further. We don't know what the balance of these forces is going to be. At least in the short run the amount of saving is strongly correlated with unemployment and the fear of unemployment. If unemployment rises and stays high that would typically drive saving up comma and if that were, common throughout the world that would drive the equilibrium real rate of return down.

So if the equilibrium interest rate falls further or at least stays low, that of course is very good news for what will of course be highly indebted governments. That said, we will need to boost growth in order that even at very low interest rates the economy can grow sufficiently to pay off what will be almost certainly a greatly increased debt burden.  And indeed was a bit of discussion at the session as to what his oral experience can tell us. The debt to GDP ratio was extremely high After World War One World War Two and rather earlier the Napoleonic wars. In the case of the Napoleonic wars in World War One the debt was reduced essentially via growth and low interest rates. That was also the case after World War 2, although inflation did play a role. So there is historical precedent for having high debt burdens and there is historical precedent for their being reduced by the joint forces of economic growth and interest rates.

In that respect QE is a minor player.  


Q. The Fed was quick and effective to launch stimulus programmes to contain the freefall in markets by providing mass scale liquidity. Warren Buffet recently commented that due to Fed intervention asset prices haven't bottomed out, making investment opportunities less attractive. Do you think the market has bottomed out? What are the asset price implications if lockdowns continue, albeit intermittently, until 2021? i.e. returns on stocks, bond yields, ETFs, safe haven assets such as gold.  Given the flight to safety we're seeing in capital outflows, what are the implications for FX rates between strong currencies (e.g. dollar, euro) and EM currencies? Could the massive scale QE cause the dollar to depreciate?


The session finished with some discussion of the above couple of questions. The difficulty of forecasting interest rates exchange rates made most people rather non-committal, beyond the observation that the US dollar always seems to stay strong in periods of panic , as people seek refuge in the world’s reserve currency. Finally, the future of the housing market. The interesting issue here is whether our experience of working from home, and the possible worries about taking public transport , might get us to a situation in which there is simply much less demand for both offices in general, but also office space,. That fall in demand may well have important effects reducing prices and rendering housing more affordable.  Another example of an equilibrating market?