Tuesday 26 February 2019

Brexit scenarios


Brexit
In November the Bank published some scenarios, https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/report/2018/eu-withdrawal-scenarios-and-monetary-and-financial-stability.  Here’s a summary.

1.      Channels
Figure 2A sets out the channels.  We move from right to left.


a.       The scenarios modelled and assumptions.
On the left we see the three scenarios modelled and next to it, the various assumptions, involvesd. These scenarios were requested by the TSC.  They are set out in  Table 3.1.1, 3.2.1, 3.3.1 and I summarise here

Scenario
Barriers
Preparedness
Econ Partnership
No customs checks, no goods barriers, some service barriers, no new trade deals. Non-tariff barriers. Loss of passporting.
Transition to 2020 sufficient for all to prepare
No deal, no transition
Customs checks, All apply common customs tariff, regulatory checks needed.  WTO means services barriers: lost passporting, lost broadcasting, transport licences needed.  In disorderly, UK loses access to existing trade agreements with EU and 3rd countries
Delays at border,
Transition to WTO
Gradual transition to WTO terms, about 3 ¼% tariff on goods. Customs checks.


Within each scenario, more and less severe variants are modelled, such as in no deal, no transition (p.6), “the UK loses existing trade arrangements that it currently has with non-EU countries through membership of the EU. The UK’s border infrastructure is assumed to be unable to cope smoothly with customs requirements. There is a pronounced increase in the return investors demand for holding sterling assets. There are spillovers across asset classes.”

b.      Evidence.
The middle column shows the range of evidence used to model the scenarios.  There are few case studies to go on, with some work on New Zealand who lost access to the UK in the 1970s, but in the middle of an oil crisis.  So the main work relies on (a) gravity equations and a trade/GDP elasticity and (b) a FDI and productivity.

The gravity equations model trade between countries with like GDP and controlling for distance, finding that more trade is with richer countries nearby.  To simulate the effects of Brexit, the idea is to look for how much more or less trade there is between similar countries (distance, relative GDP) who are and are not in trade agreements.  Note that leaving a trade agreement might stop trade between A and B, but it might be taken up between A and C, so this has to be controlled for.  After these terms are estimated, the loss of trade is multiplied by the elasticity of GDP with respect to trade.  This is taken from studies like Feyer which are in turn reduced form estimates of episodes, such as the closure of the Suez canal on GDP per person. 

The FDI link is that FDI might boost domestic productivity via spillovers to the host country.

As a matter of data, most of the work is done in by the gravity equations since the trade elasticity is much larger.  We don’t however, have much a model for services.

There are other effects such as exchange rates and financial conditions, perhaps due to uncertainty. These are harder to pin down.  Still harder is the timing of these events. 

c.       Prospects
The prospects for GDP and inflation etc. are scenarios via some modelling.  There is an interesting paragraph, p. 4 on the difficult issue of timing

“Speed of adjustment:
Given the lack of precedents, there is uncertainty over the speed of adjustment to
reduced openness….
-  A range of evidence suggests that the impact of introducing frictions such as tariffs and customs
checks at the border comes through quickly. A substantial number of firms have little experience
with customs checks and, for many, business models and supply chain management could be
significantly disrupted by delays at the border. Intelligence from the Bank’s Agents suggests that
uncertainty has deterred some companies from investing in preparatory actions, and it is likely that
the corporate sector is generally not yet well equipped to cope were the UK to leave the EU
without a transition period.
-  The discrete nature of some non-tariff barriers means that they have the potential to have a rapid
effect on trade. One example is in financial services where, if the relevant regulations do not allow
for the service to be provided cross border, then the impact on the supply capacity of the economy
may be immediate and coincident with the direct effect to demand.
-  Sectoral evidence points to a need to reallocate capital and labour as patterns of production
change in response to changes in the cost of trade. If resources are unable to move seamlessly this
will quickly disrupt supply.”

The report goes on

“The level of preparedness of businesses and infrastructure (such as ports, excise and customs systems and
transport operations) will be important in determining how the economy adjusts to new barriers. The
extent of any disruption at the border and to transport and financial services will depend on preparations
made by firms, the authorities and on policy decisions yet to be taken by both sides.”

In this way, we can understand the scenario modelling in Chart A.

It sets out two broad scenarios, partnership and no deal.  Around those scenarios are different versions, as set out above, with the lowest scenario the no deal, no transition.
 

As can be seen the lower scenario with no deal and no transition shows a steep fall in GDP with then a recovery but with an endstate 10% below the May 2016 trend.

Some other points.
1.      Non-tariff barriers have risen a good deal, see below.
And as the report notes:

“NTBs are particularly important because they have the potential to have a rapid effect on trade. This is
because the discrete nature of some barriers means an exporter can either supply the goods or services, or
they cannot. One example is financial services, where if the relevant regulations do not allow for the service
to be provided across borders, then the NTB could impact on trade immediately and fully following the UK’s
exit from the EU. Similarly, under current regulations some services – such as broadcasting – cannot be
exported to the EU without direct authorisation within member states.”

2.      Different sectors
You might think that different sectors are differently exposed.  One is via EU labour


The other is via exposure to possible changes in border and behind border arrangements. The heat map suggests agriculture is particularly exposed.


3.      Direct effects on inflation from exchange rates and food tariffs
The long run contributions depend on both shares in spending and also changes in prices.  Changes in prices are mostly in food and transport as are the contributions: